Social Europe

politics, economy and employment & labour

  • Themes
    • European digital sphere
    • Recovery and resilience
  • Publications
    • Books
    • Dossiers
    • Occasional Papers
    • Research Essays
    • Brexit Paper Series
  • Podcast
  • Videos
  • Newsletter

Why A Rebooted ESM Is Much Better Than An EMF

Marcello Minenna 1st February 2018

Marcello Minenna

Marcello Minenna

After the controversial European Monetary Fund (EMF) proposal by the European Commission of December 2017, it’s clear that the debate about the future role and structure of the European Stability Mechanism is not over. It will only end when the Euro area benefits from a unified government bond market with a single risk-free yield curve. This will not be easy to achieve while respecting what markets think of the sovereign risk of peripheral countries, but it can be done. The road is not, however, the EMF envisaged within a plethora of proposals from the European Commission. The first, fundamental step would be certainly to transform the European Stability Mechanism (the bailout fund established in 2012) but into an insurer of last resort for the public debt of all Eurozone countries.

These are the key features of my idea. Riskier members of the reformed ESM should pay insurance premiums, that would increase the fund’s capital by many orders in comparison to the current level of €80billion that is inadequate to bail-out even a large-sized economy like Spain, and would boost its investment capacity. The more the sovereign risk of a country, the higher the premium to be paid. It’s not rocket science, but a simple, effective mechanism that resembles the functioning of a classic derivative instrument, the Credit Default Swap. Using more technical jargon, the premium is needed to hedge the difference between the credit risk of the different Member countries and the Eurozone average. An appreciable feature of this mechanism would therefore be the fact the size of the insurance premium would be determined by market evaluations of credit risk so far from being driven by strong political influences.

The process of insuring debt should happen gradually; as the old bond issues of each government come to maturity, the ESM would substitute them with new tranches of a common guaranteed Euro area debt. After completing this operation of risk-sharing (not less than ten years, according to my estimates), Eurozone countries would no longer be allowed to issue public debt independently from this common ESM issue program. Or, putting it another way: at the end of this sequence each Eurozone country would give up its fiscal autonomy in exchange for a full mutualization of its past government debt.

In the 10-year long process of transition, indeed, premiums paid for the ESM guarantee represent a shield against potential fiscally irresponsible behavior of a “free-rider” country. The contribution scheme in fact would discourage reckless fiscal policies, because it’s understood that more debt would mean more credit risk to be insured and then it could be issued only with higher contributions to the reformed ESM.

Real economy investments

In normal times, the proceeds of the reformed ESM would be invested in the real economies of Member States. Again, it would be useful to use an intuitive criterion of proportionality: higher premiums should guarantee a greater quota of investments. The ESM’s financial backing would be granted only to highly profitable projects. In this perspective, fixed capital formation has the highest multiplier across all components of public expenditure, especially if concentrated in high-potential, but depressed areas like southern Italy. Obviously, there would be a problem of accountability related to investment management activities (selection, administration, revision). This could be addressed by transferring all powers to a supranational, independent institution (e.g. the European Fiscal Board) with a neutral view based only on objective economic indicators of profitability.

Our job is keeping you informed!


Subscribe to our free newsletter and stay up to date with the latest Social Europe content.


We will never send you spam and you can unsubscribe anytime.

Thank you!

Please check your inbox and click on the link in the confirmation email to complete your newsletter subscription.

.

By construction, this design of a reformed ESM will produce a convergence of government yields towards a single curve for the entire Eurozone in a form even stronger than the one experimented with in the first years of life of the Euro (until the crisis of 2007-2008). In fact, a fully mutualized debt naturally implies a homogeneous credit risk evaluation, since national public debts would eventually disappear and merge within a Eurozone one. In this way we will enjoy the re-birth of Eurobonds, even if in a synthetic form, managed by a reformed ESM that would accordingly assume many of the powers of the current Ministers of Finance of the Member States and would make the proposed reform of the European Commission readily obsolete.

To conclude, I’m supporting a radical proposal, “peripheral-friendly” of course, but one that is respectful of market evaluations and that moves towards a federalist Europe. An ESM 2.0 based on risk-sharing, a single yield curve and the rebooting of fruitful public investments with a higher degree of flexibility than today could form the skeleton of a future federal budget that can rely on the possibility of issuing Eurozone supranational bonds.

This concrete, market-based concept represents an alternative to the German proposal of transforming the ESM into a severe fiscal authority independent of political bodies and inserting creditor participation clauses within the government bonds of the different member states.

Obviously, this would have a major impact on current Eurozone financial infrastructures. The EU institutions should support the process of convergence with various other measures: for example, in the early years, the architecture of the Fiscal Compact should be properly harmonized to exclude the premium paid to the reformed ESM from the calculations related to the structural balance. In the end, with a mutualized debt, the same Fiscal Compact regulation would not be needed anymore. Moreover, ECB support should be guaranteed through the prosecution of its asset purchase programs for a reasonable extended timeframe.

Of course, it may not be politically feasible given the current circumstances that are pushing in the opposite direction towards a segregation of risks within each country of origin. This process is on stand-by¸ waiting for the results of Italian elections, but it will restart in full force immediately after they take place. However, recent developments do not make me optimistic about the future of the Eurozone integration process: the proposal for European Safe Bonds is gaining a lot of traction but it’s not that brilliant an idea – these are fake Eurobonds without any real risk-sharing between Member countries and pose more problems than they solve…


We need your support


Social Europe is an independent publisher and we believe in freely available content. For this model to be sustainable, however, we depend on the solidarity of our readers. Become a Social Europe member for less than 5 Euro per month and help us produce more articles, podcasts and videos. Thank you very much for your support!

Become a Social Europe Member

Marcello Minenna

Marcello Minenna is head of the quantitative analysis unit in Consob (the Italian Securities and Exchange Commission). He has taught quantitative finance at Bocconi University and at the London Graduate School of Mathematical Finance. He is a regular writer for the Wall Street Journal and Corriere della Sera and is a member of an advisory group which supports the economic analysis of the biggest Italian trade union, CGIL.

Home ・ Economy ・ Why A Rebooted ESM Is Much Better Than An EMF

Most Popular Posts

schools,Sweden,Swedish,voucher,choice Sweden’s schools: Milton Friedman’s wet dreamLisa Pelling
world order,Russia,China,Europe,United States,US The coming world orderMarc Saxer
south working,remote work ‘South working’: the future of remote workAntonio Aloisi and Luisa Corazza
Russia,Putin,assets,oligarchs Seizing the assets of Russian oligarchsBranko Milanovic
Russians,support,war,Ukraine Why do Russians support the war against Ukraine?Svetlana Erpyleva

Most Recent Posts

Gazprom,Putin,Nordstream,Putin,Schröder How the public loses out when politicians cash inKatharina Pistor
defence,europe,spending Ukraine and Europe’s defence spendingValerio Alfonso Bruno and Adriano Cozzolino
North Atlantic Treaty Organization,NATO,Ukraine The Ukraine war and NATO’s renewed credibilityPaul Rogers
transnational list,European constituency,European elections,European public sphere A European constituency for a European public sphereDomènec Ruiz Devesa
hydrogen,gas,LNG,REPowerEU EU hydrogen targets—a neo-colonial resource grabPascoe Sabido and Chloé Mikolajczak

Other Social Europe Publications

The transatlantic relationship
Women and the coronavirus crisis
RE No. 12: Why No Economic Democracy in Sweden?
US election 2020
Corporate taxation in a globalised era

ETUI advertisement

Bilan social / Social policy in the EU: state of play 2021 and perspectives

The new edition of the Bilan social 2021, co-produced by the European Social Observatory (OSE) and the European Trade Union Institute (ETUI), reveals that while EU social policy-making took a blow in 2020, 2021 was guided by the re-emerging social aspirations of the European Commission and the launch of several important initiatives. Against the background of Covid-19, climate change and the debate on the future of Europe, the French presidency of the Council of the EU and the von der Leyen commission must now be closely scrutinised by EU citizens and social stakeholders.


AVAILABLE HERE

Eurofound advertisement

Living and working in Europe 2021

The Covid-19 pandemic continued to be a defining force in 2021, and Eurofound continued its work of examining and recording the many and diverse impacts across the EU. Living and working in Europe 2021 provides a snapshot of the changes to employment, work and living conditions in Europe. It also summarises the agency’s findings on issues such as gender equality in employment, wealth inequality and labour shortages. These will have a significant bearing on recovery from the pandemic, resilience in the face of the war in Ukraine and a successful transition to a green and digital future.


AVAILABLE HERE

Foundation for European Progressive Studies Advertisement

EU Care Atlas: a new interactive data map showing how care deficits affect the gender earnings gap in the EU

Browse through the EU Care Atlas, a new interactive data map to help uncover what the statistics are often hiding: how care deficits directly feed into the gender earnings gap.

While attention is often focused on the gender pay gap (13%), the EU Care Atlas brings to light the more worrisome and complex picture of women’s economic inequalities. The pay gap is just one of three main elements that explain the overall earnings gap, which is estimated at 36.7%. The EU Care Atlas illustrates the urgent need to look beyond the pay gap and understand the interplay between the overall earnings gap and care imbalances.


BROWSE THROUGH THE MAP

Hans Böckler Stiftung Advertisement

Towards a new Minimum Wage Policy in Germany and Europe: WSI minimum wage report 2022

The past year has seen a much higher political profile for the issue of minimum wages, not only in Germany, which has seen fresh initiatives to tackle low pay, but also in those many other countries in Europe that have embarked on substantial and sustained increases in statutory minimum wages. One key benchmark in determining what should count as an adequate minimum wage is the threshold of 60 per cent of the median wage, a ratio that has also played a role in the European Commission's proposals for an EU-level policy on minimum wages. This year's WSI Minimum Wage Report highlights the feasibility of achieving minimum wages that meet this criterion, given the political will. And with an increase to 12 euro per hour planned for autumn 2022, Germany might now find itself promoted from laggard to minimum-wage trailblazer.


FREE DOWNLOAD

About Social Europe

Our Mission

Article Submission

Membership

Advertisements

Legal Disclosure

Privacy Policy

Copyright

Social Europe ISSN 2628-7641

Social Europe Archives

Search Social Europe

Themes Archive

Politics Archive

Economy Archive

Society Archive

Ecology Archive

Follow us on social media

Follow us on Facebook

Follow us on Twitter

Follow us on LinkedIn

Follow us on YouTube