Social Europe

politics, economy and employment & labour

  • Themes
    • European digital sphere
    • Recovery and resilience
  • Publications
    • Books
    • Dossiers
    • Occasional Papers
    • Research Essays
    • Brexit Paper Series
  • Podcast
  • Videos
  • Newsletter

The ‘Tax Shift’: A Surrealist Fantasy

Jan Drahokoupil 15th March 2016

Jan Drahokoupil

Jan Drahokoupil

Reducing taxes on labour – personal income taxes and employers’ and employees’ social security contributions – is often seen as key to increasing employment levels. The latest crop of country-specific recommendations issued by the European Commission is a case in point. But the rationale for such a ‘tax shift’ is relatively weak. For most countries, it is likely to represent yet another much-talked-about reform with little relevance for actual employment and economic outcomes.

Higher labour costs are assumed to reduce the demand for workers. Moreover, high labour taxation may lower incentives for the unemployed and inactive to take up work as it means that the additional income to be derived from employment is too limited to fuel the motivation to work. Referring to these two reasons, the Commission (EC) has advocated a shift in taxation away from labour to the ‘least distortionary taxes’, including taxes on consumption, housing and other property, and environmental taxes (European Commission 2015: 24).

The arguments for shifting the tax burden to property and activities that harm the environment are strong, but, for various reasons, there has been little action on these fronts. The ‘tax shift’ debate thus in practice boils down to the advice to shift taxation away from labour and capital income to consumption. However, it is hard to come up with convincing grounds for this recommendation.

The method used by the EC to identify countries in need of reducing taxation is simple, but hopelessly arbitrary: countries are found to be in need of reducing their tax rates if their taxation levels happen to be significantly above the EU average (see European Commission 2015 and various country-specific recommendations).

The idea that consumption taxes are somewhat less harmful relies on empirical modelling by the OECD (2010). The OECD’s own research, however, questions the rationale for the tax shift towards consumption as it confirms that consumption taxes affect employment and hours of work in pretty much the same way as do income taxes. What can be firmly established, however, is that such a shift is regressive as it affects the lower income groups.

Our job is keeping you informed!


Subscribe to our free newsletter and stay up to date with the latest Social Europe content.


We will never send you spam and you can unsubscribe anytime.

Thank you!

Please check your inbox and click on the link in the confirmation email to complete your newsletter subscription.

.

Where’s the link?

Empirically, it is difficult to separate the effect of taxes from other elements of the policy mix in individual countries. Nevertheless, a comparison of employment and tax levels in the EU, as shown in a figure taken from the ETUI’s 2016 Benchmarking Working Europe report, shows no relationship between the two. In fact, many countries with very high employment levels impose steep labour taxes. As a result, countries identified by the Commission as in need of reducing taxes on labour – i.e. Belgium, Czechia, France, Italy, Hungary, Finland and also the ‘borderline’ cases of Germany, the Netherlands, Austria, and Sweden –  include these best-performing countries.

Where the crisis countries suffering from high unemployment are concerned, reducing labour costs through lowering taxation does not seem to offer any immediate respite either. As shown also by the EC’s own labour market analyses, adjustment strategies based on a reduction in labour costs have reached their limits, with countries characterised by high unemployment recording falling labour costs also.

The second rationale pointing to a possible lack of incentives to take up work is sounder.

It is plausible that high labour taxation levels may create incentive problems for the inactive or some groups of workers. They may shy away from additional employment effort due to the high taxation imposed on the additional income. Potentially affected groups include the inactive, the unemployed, second earners in a household, and low-wage earners. The EC’s analysis finds a number of such traps in individual countries (European Commission 2015: 26-27). However, even in this case, countries suffering from such traps include cases of both worst and best performance in terms of employment among the affected groups.

Finally, the ‘tax-shift argument’ has been reinterpreted in a popular version that emphasises a need to reduce social security contributions (SSC) paid by the employers in particular. Such an argument may be intuitively appealing to employers seeking to reduce any taxes that they are obliged to pay, but there is no reason why they should matter more than other components of labour taxation – in fact, they may be less relevant to incentives for workers. Empirically, there is in the EU no correlation between employer SSCs and employment levels.


We need your support


Social Europe is an independent publisher and we believe in freely available content. For this model to be sustainable, however, we depend on the solidarity of our readers. Become a Social Europe member for less than 5 Euro per month and help us produce more articles, podcasts and videos. Thank you very much for your support!

Become a Social Europe Member

Nevertheless, this thinking informed the 2015 tax shift in Belgium, reducing employer social security contributions from 33% to 25%. Ironically, despite having the highest level of taxation on labour and a unique tax mix heavily subsidizing car use, that country was a boring European average as far as its levels of employer SSC were concerned. Once again, Belgian surrealism helpfully illustrated the futility of efforts on the European level.

etuifig1Figure Tax wedge on labour (average wage) and overall employment rate (20-64 years), 2014 

* data are available for 2013 only.

Note: Tax wedge on labour: The difference between the wage costs to the employer of a worker on an average wage, including personal income tax and compulsory social security contributions, and the amount of net income that the worker receives.  Source: European Commission tax and benefits database based on OECD data (European Commission, 2015).

Jan Drahokoupil

Jan Drahokoupil is Senior Researcher at the European Trade Union Institute (ETUI) in Brussels.

Home ・ Politics ・ The ‘Tax Shift’: A Surrealist Fantasy

Most Popular Posts

schools,Sweden,Swedish,voucher,choice Sweden’s schools: Milton Friedman’s wet dreamLisa Pelling
world order,Russia,China,Europe,United States,US The coming world orderMarc Saxer
south working,remote work ‘South working’: the future of remote workAntonio Aloisi and Luisa Corazza
Russia,Putin,assets,oligarchs Seizing the assets of Russian oligarchsBranko Milanovic
Russians,support,war,Ukraine Why do Russians support the war against Ukraine?Svetlana Erpyleva

Most Recent Posts

Sakharov,nuclear,Khrushchev Unhappy birthday, Andrei SakharovNina L Khrushcheva
Gazprom,Putin,Nordstream,Putin,Schröder How the public loses out when politicians cash inKatharina Pistor
defence,europe,spending Ukraine and Europe’s defence spendingValerio Alfonso Bruno and Adriano Cozzolino
North Atlantic Treaty Organization,NATO,Ukraine The Ukraine war and NATO’s renewed credibilityPaul Rogers
transnational list,European constituency,European elections,European public sphere A European constituency for a European public sphereDomènec Ruiz Devesa

Other Social Europe Publications

The transatlantic relationship
Women and the coronavirus crisis
RE No. 12: Why No Economic Democracy in Sweden?
US election 2020
Corporate taxation in a globalised era

Hans Böckler Stiftung Advertisement

Towards a new Minimum Wage Policy in Germany and Europe: WSI minimum wage report 2022

The past year has seen a much higher political profile for the issue of minimum wages, not only in Germany, which has seen fresh initiatives to tackle low pay, but also in those many other countries in Europe that have embarked on substantial and sustained increases in statutory minimum wages. One key benchmark in determining what should count as an adequate minimum wage is the threshold of 60 per cent of the median wage, a ratio that has also played a role in the European Commission's proposals for an EU-level policy on minimum wages. This year's WSI Minimum Wage Report highlights the feasibility of achieving minimum wages that meet this criterion, given the political will. And with an increase to 12 euro per hour planned for autumn 2022, Germany might now find itself promoted from laggard to minimum-wage trailblazer.


FREE DOWNLOAD

ETUI advertisement

Bilan social / Social policy in the EU: state of play 2021 and perspectives

The new edition of the Bilan social 2021, co-produced by the European Social Observatory (OSE) and the European Trade Union Institute (ETUI), reveals that while EU social policy-making took a blow in 2020, 2021 was guided by the re-emerging social aspirations of the European Commission and the launch of several important initiatives. Against the background of Covid-19, climate change and the debate on the future of Europe, the French presidency of the Council of the EU and the von der Leyen commission must now be closely scrutinised by EU citizens and social stakeholders.


AVAILABLE HERE

Eurofound advertisement

Living and working in Europe 2021

The Covid-19 pandemic continued to be a defining force in 2021, and Eurofound continued its work of examining and recording the many and diverse impacts across the EU. Living and working in Europe 2021 provides a snapshot of the changes to employment, work and living conditions in Europe. It also summarises the agency’s findings on issues such as gender equality in employment, wealth inequality and labour shortages. These will have a significant bearing on recovery from the pandemic, resilience in the face of the war in Ukraine and a successful transition to a green and digital future.


AVAILABLE HERE

Foundation for European Progressive Studies Advertisement

EU Care Atlas: a new interactive data map showing how care deficits affect the gender earnings gap in the EU

Browse through the EU Care Atlas, a new interactive data map to help uncover what the statistics are often hiding: how care deficits directly feed into the gender earnings gap.

While attention is often focused on the gender pay gap (13%), the EU Care Atlas brings to light the more worrisome and complex picture of women’s economic inequalities. The pay gap is just one of three main elements that explain the overall earnings gap, which is estimated at 36.7%. The EU Care Atlas illustrates the urgent need to look beyond the pay gap and understand the interplay between the overall earnings gap and care imbalances.


BROWSE THROUGH THE MAP

About Social Europe

Our Mission

Article Submission

Membership

Advertisements

Legal Disclosure

Privacy Policy

Copyright

Social Europe ISSN 2628-7641

Social Europe Archives

Search Social Europe

Themes Archive

Politics Archive

Economy Archive

Society Archive

Ecology Archive

Follow us on social media

Follow us on Facebook

Follow us on Twitter

Follow us on LinkedIn

Follow us on YouTube